To Lift or Not to Lift? The U.S. Crude Oil Export Ban: Implications for Price and Energy Security
Table of Contents
Author(s)
Kenneth B. Medlock III
James A. Baker, III, and Susan G. Baker Fellow in Energy and Resource Economics | Senior Director, Center for Energy StudiesLifting the 40-year-old US crude oil export ban would raise US crude oil prices back toward parity with prices for internationally traded crude oils of similar quality, increase upstream and midstream investment, and improve US energy security. Moreover, this would be accomplished without raising domestic gasoline prices. These are the primary conclusions of the study “To Lift or Not to Lift? The U.S. Crude Oil Ban: Implications for Price and Energy Security,” which contributes a new perspective to a growing recent literature examining US oil export policy. In comparison to most other research, however, this study employs a different approach to characterizing and analyzing oil export policy. Moreover, it was completed after the recent collapse in oil prices, so it evaluates the issue over a much wider range of global oil price environments, from $30 to $150 per barrel. In doing so it provides a robust view of the implications of current export policy and the impact that lifting the ban would have.
The crude oil being produced in the US from unconventional plays such as the Bakken and Eagle Ford is generally very light and of high quality. Absent the ban on exports, these crudes would compete with crudes of similar quality in the international market and would be accordingly priced. However, the export ban presents a constraint that ultimately drives the price of these domestic crude oils to be discounted. Moreover, these discounts can be expected to persist into the future as long as crude oil exports are banned. This occurs because the supply of domestic light crude oil exceeds the light crude oil processing capacity of US refiners who are backing out heavier, lower quality oils to run domestically produced light crude oils.
Previous studies have focused on how West Texas Intermediate (WTI) has moved relative to the international marker crude, Brent. WTI, the US crude oil benchmark, priced slightly above Brent prior to 2011, but the ramp up of US and Canadian unconventional oil production and the resultant influx of crude oil to Cushing, Oklahoma, has resulted in WTI being discounted relative to Brent in recent years. Rather than focus exclusively on the WTI-Brent relationship, this study evaluates a much broader set of crude oils to better understand where domestic crude oils would price absent the export ban.
To this end, the study employs a hedonic pricing method to evaluate how differences in crude oil qualities translate to pricing for 30 internationally traded crude oils. The analysis reveals that gravity (API) and sulfur content are critical determinants of a crude oil’s price relative to Brent. Since data on the price of domestic light crude oils from shale is not available prior to their production, the hedonic pricing method allows the assessment of where these crude oils would price in an international market setting unconstrained by the US export ban. Based on the analysis, it is demonstrated that the export ban is already binding, thus resulting in domestic crude oil prices seeing, in some cases, fairly significant discounts, even in a low international price environment.
The study also explains why we should continue to expect US refineries to process substantial volumes of imported crudes, even with growing domestic production. Crude oil is not a homogenous commodity, and different crude oils are not perfect substitutes for one another. Most light crude oil being produced from shale has a higher gravity than WTI, Brent, and other international crudes and contains less sulfur than the heavier, primarily imported, crudes that US refineries have been geared to process. Due to the logistics of where crude oil has historically been sourced, US refiners have invested billions of dollars to be able to adequately handle heavy, sour crude oils rather than the more expensive light, sweet crude oils. Heavy, sour crude oils require more expensive and intensive processing to yield highly valued refined products, such as gasoline and diesel. When a refinery sinks capital into developing this capability, it has access to lower priced crude oils. In order to provide the incentive to refine lighter crude oils, those typically higher priced barrels must be discounted so that their pricing is more in line with the heavy, less expensive crude oil the refiner would otherwise purchase. Because of this dynamic, domestic refiners at the heavier end of the spectrum will continue to import heavy crude oils. Moreover, if price discounts on the domestically produced light barrels are persistent, investment in lighter processing capability will be forthcoming. In either case, the US refining sector will continue to import heavy barrels in line with its capabilities.
The study provides a simple graphical explanation of what it would mean for domestic light crude oil prices if US refineries were to use additional domestically produced light crude oils to back out imports of heavy, sour crude oils. Prior to the US shale revolution, the supply of light oil to domestic refiners originated from both domestic and imported sources, and the price of US light crude was at parity with imported crude oils of similar quality. However, the rapidly growing domestic supply of light crude oil has backed out imports of light crude oil and exceeded US refinery capacity for processing light crude oil. Since the excess light crude cannot be exported, producers are faced with either shutting in some light oil production or discounting the price of their output to encourage refineries to reduce their runs of medium crude oils, instead running additional light oil. Thus, the price of domestic light crude oil drops to parity with the lower quality oil it is replacing in refineries. As heavier and heavier crude oils are backed out by domestic production, the discount relative to the international price for light crude oil will grow in order to provide the price incentive for US refiners to substitute the light crude oil for the heavier crudes that the refineries were designed to process.
Data on crude oil imports reveal that domestic production has already backed out imported crudes of similar gravity and is now backing out heavier crudes. Using the hedonic pricing method, the study assesses the resultant discount at different international oil price ($30 to $150 per barrel) environments, given the range of API gravity and sulfur contents of the heavy crude that domestic light crude oil is replacing.
The study also assesses the impact on US gasoline prices of an end to the oil export ban. In particular, it addresses the question, “Would higher prices for domestic crude oils translate into higher prices at the pump?” Similarly to other studies, the analysis dispels this notion. Since refined products can be traded freely on the international market, the discounted prices of US crude have not translated into discounted prices of refined products. Instead, US refiners are able to buy domestic light crude oils at a discount to the international price, then sell refined products at international prices. The lack of a restriction on trade of refined products allows domestic and international wholesale prices to harmonize, meaning domestic refiners are able to retain the domestic crude oil price discount as additional margin, a point the study highlights as a no cost call option that refiners hold on domestic crude oil purchases. It also notes that not all domestic refiners see this benefit, a result owing to the different configurations, and hence crude qualities, each processes. Data supports this notion. In particular, beginning in 2011, the price of WTI started diverging on a lower path relative to both Brent crude oil and US Gulf Coast gasoline prices. Statistical analysis indicates that after 2010, WTI has been on average $10 per barrel lower relative to gasoline, while the price of Brent has been about $3 per barrel higher relative to gasoline. As the US has been a net exporter of refined products since 2011, the arbitrage point for international gasoline has moved away from the Gulf Coast. The shift in the relative price relationship between international crude oils and US-produced gasoline reflects the cost to transport the gasoline to a new point of arbitrage offshore. Moreover, this transition has been driven primarily by the sharp reduction in US demand that has left the US with more than enough refining capacity to meet its internal needs, and could easily reverse course should US demand recover significantly. The large discount of WTI relative to gasoline and Brent, however, reflects the refinery dynamics discussed above.
The study also notes that although eliminating the export ban would reduce rents to some US refiners, it would be transformative for US crude oil producers (assuming that the shale resource base has a long productive life). Significant capital would flow into the upstream as well as into pipeline and other infrastructure development, which would ultimately drive a dissipation of the discount on US light oil as greater trade is facilitated. Regarding refiners, even with unrestricted oil exports, low US natural gas prices still bode well for their international competitiveness. Moreover, light crude oil imports would still be substituted by domestic production, and domestic refineries would be optimized as they would import and process the heavier, lower quality crude oils for which they were designed.
Lastly, the study reveals that removing the oil export ban would generate distinct energy security benefits for the US, a result that is counterintuitive to some. Following the voluminous literature on the subject, energy security generally refers to the concept of ensuring an adequate supply of oil at a stable and reasonable price. This goal is sought because there is a strong empirical correlation between macroeconomic malaise and unexpected and extreme movements in the price of oil. Diversification of oil supply options, especially by adding supply from stable producing countries, is one means of mitigating the risk of an oil market disruption. To this end, the US shale oil boom has already provided significant energy security benefits. Over the period from 2008 to 2013, increased oil output from the US has offset the production declines in countries such as Libya, Algeria, Syria, and Iran that were due to local strife or sanctions. In the absence of US shale oil output, prices would have been much higher and much more volatile. However, the lack of ability for US oil producers to export is capping the extension of this benefit by leaving some domestic investment unrealized, and ultimately limiting the amount of low-risk oil supply that can reach the international market. Since oil prices transmit to consumers through the price of refined products, by not allowing US oil production to have a larger impact on global oil prices, and hence petroleum product prices, current policy is actually compromising domestic energy security. In effect, the oil export ban does nothing to insulate US consumers from unexpected movements in the international price of refined products, so it does not provide any broad energy security benefit.
More generally, the study highlights that the importance of the US as a potential source of incremental supply over the longer term cannot be overstated. However, the role of the US as a stable supplier to global markets is conditional on the ability of US production volumes to access the global market. The US could take a leadership role in transforming global trade in crude oil that would carry significant geopolitical benefits and, more generally, establish the US as a trusted partner in discussions focused on expanding international trade.
This material may be quoted or reproduced without prior permission, provided appropriate credit is given to the author and Rice University’s Baker Institute for Public Policy. The views expressed herein are those of the individual author(s), and do not necessarily represent the views of Rice University’s Baker Institute for Public Policy.