Reflecting on the Budget Control Act of 2011 and Its Relevance Now
Table of Contents
Author(s)
John W. Diamond
Edward A. and Hermena Hancock Kelly Senior Fellow in Public Finance | Director, Center for Public FinanceAutumn Engebretson
Senior Analyst at 547 EnergyShare this Publication
- Print This Publication
- Cite This Publication Copy Citation
John W. Diamond and Autumn Engebretson, "Reflecting on the Budget Control Act of 2011 and Its Relevance Now" (Houston: Rice University’s Baker Institute for Public Policy, February 16, 2023), https://doi.org/10.25613/59ET-N314.
Introduction
With the 2023 debt-ceiling negotiations ongoing and likely to be contentious, now is a good time to look back at the 2011 debt-ceiling crisis and the legislation that was passed in response to it. The main law enacted was the Budget Control Act of 2011 (BCA). What did it aim to do, and did it achieve those aims? How effective was the BCA? Given that the BCA expired at the end of FY 2021, should Congress and President Biden enact similar legislation moving forward?
The 2011 Crisis
The debt ceiling is a legislated limit on how much the U.S. Treasury can borrow and it also affects how much can be spent on debt repayment. Because the U.S. government spends more than its income, the debt ceiling is periodically raised — and sometimes suspended — to avoid default on the government’s debt.
In the several decades prior to 2011, increases in the debt ceiling normally occurred without debate. However, the significant and rapid growth in the federal budget deficit and debt following the Great Recession[1] led to calls for a reduction in the level of government spending. In 2011, the deficit as a percent of GDP was 8.4%, after peaking at 9.8% in 2009. Figure 1 shows the sharp rise in debt held by the public as a share of GDP during this time. It rose from 38.7% in 2008 to 64.3% in 2011.[2] It has since increased to 96.4% in 2021.
Many politicians and pundits argued that, without intervention, the U.S. debt would continue to grow as a share of GDP and have adverse effects on U.S. economic growth. The debt-ceiling crisis centered on the argument made by House Republicans that in exchange for an increase in the debt ceiling, the president would have to agree to a reduction in government spending and the federal deficit. Note, however, that there was bipartisan concern about the level of federal budget deficits and debt, as evidenced by the vote on HR 1954 (a bill to increase the debt ceiling as President Obama requested) on May 31, 2011: It failed by a vote of 318 to 97, with 236 Republicans and 82 Democrats voting against the bill.[3]
Figure 1 — Debt as a Share of GDP
What Did the BCA Do?
In response to the crisis, the BCA was enacted in 2011. The BCA increased the debt ceiling by $400 billion in August 2011 and allowed President Obama to request additional increases of $500 billion and $1.2 trillion. The BCA included $917 billion in direct spending reductions over 10 years to offset the initial increase of $900 billion in the debt ceiling, with only $21 billion of the increase occurring in 2012. The $1.2 trillion increase in the debt ceiling was contingent on efforts to reduce the spending by an equal amount. To this end, the BCA created the Joint Committee of Deficit Reduction, required a vote on a balanced budget amendment, and stipulated across-the-board cuts to mandatory and discretionary spending if Congress failed to act to offset the $1.2 trillion increase in the debt ceiling.
This effort to reduce federal government spending relied on discretionary spending caps and automatic reductions in mandatory spending. Total reductions were to equal $1.2 trillion after debt service cost reductions ($216 billion) and nine years of annual cuts to defense ($55 billion per year) and non-defense ($55 billion per year) spending.[4]
Triggering or Avoiding Sequestration
The discretionary spending caps from FY 2012 to FY 2021 effectively set the maximum amount of appropriated spending that Congress could pass. Sequestration was the enforcement mechanism; if spending exceeded the caps, it automatically triggered spending reductions. The BCA implemented the mandatory spending caps suggested by the National Commission on Fiscal Responsibility and Reform (often referred to as Simpson-Bowles from the names of co-chairs Alan Simpson and Erskine Bowles).
Under the BCA, the sequester could have been avoided if Congress passed legislation by Jan. 15, 2012, to reduce the deficit by $1.2 trillion from FY 2012 to FY 2021, but this was not accomplished, and the process of automatic spending reduction (i.e., sequestration) began Jan. 2, 2013, but was quickly postponed to March 1 by the American Taxpayer Relief Act of 2012 (ATRA).
Because discretionary spending is almost evenly split between defense and non-defense spending and there were significant exemptions in the non-defense category[5] — e.g., exempt accounts included Social Security and the Department of Veterans Affairs — the spending cuts placed a distinct burden on defense spending. Spending reductions were to be split evenly between defense and non-defense spending, but the exemptions to large budget items made the effect on the non-exempt programs disproportionately large. The reduction in discretionary defense spending was 9.8% in FY 2014, and the reduction in non-defense spending was 7.4%.[6]
Certain areas of spending are not subject to the limits put in place by the BCA. Two such areas are Overseas Contingency Operations (OCO) (including spending for the global war on terrorism) and emergency spending. Disaster relief, wildfire suppression, and safeguards to fraud and abuse are also not subject to limits.[7] Exempting these items allowed for quick fiscal action in emergencies and limited the long-term budgetary effects of single events requiring government outlays.
What Legislation has Occurred Since the BCA?
Since the passage of the BCA there have been five significant pieces of legislation that have altered the timing of the planned reductions in the deficit. They are the ATRA, the Bipartisan Budget Act of 2013 (BBA 2013), the Bipartisan Budget Act of 2015 (BBA 2015), the Bipartisan Budget Act of 2018 (BBA 2018), and the Bipartisan Budget Act of 2019 (BBA 2019).[8] All of these acts increased limits in spending, although with varied effects on the overall efficacy of the measures put in place by the BCA.
The ATRA made significant changes to the BCA, postponing any potential sequestration from occurring from Jan. 2, 2013, to March 1, 2013. Enforcement of discretionary spending limits was also postponed to March 27, 2013. In total, this reduced BCA spending reductions by $8 billion split evenly across defense and non-defense for FY 2013 and FY 2014.[9] The sequester was also reduced in size from $109 billion to $85 billion, which was counteracted by further spending cap reductions and changes in retirement account revenues.[10]
The BBA 2013, approved in December 2013, increased spending caps for defense and non-defense categories by $22.4 billion for FY 2014 and by $9 billion for FY 2015. It also extended sequestration through FY 2023 for mandatory spending categories. Spending cap increases were offset by changes in retirement accounts, reduced cost-of-living adjustments, and other minor policy changes.[11]
The BBA 2015, approved in November 2015, suspended the debt ceiling through March 2017 and increased BCA discretionary limits in 2016 by $50 billion and in 2017 by $30 billion, split equally between defense and non-defense spending. To offset these increases, sequestration was extended an additional year to 2025, Medicare reimbursements were lowered, and other changes were made to compliance measures.[12]
The BBA 2018, signed by President Trump in February 2018, raised BCA discretionary limits in 2018 and 2019 by a total of $242.4 billion, $165 billion of which was in defense. Mandatory spending reductions were also extended, with reductions disproportionately affecting non-defense spending.[13]
The BBA 2019, signed by President Trump in August 2019, raised BCA discretionary limits from $1.12 trillion in 2020 to $1.29 trillion, and from $1.15 trillion in 2021 to $1.30 trillion. This specifically increased defense spending by $90 billion and non-defense by $78 billion in 2020 and established higher OCO targets of $80 billion for 2020 and $77 billion in 2021. The BBA 2019 also extended the sequester for another two years to FY 2029, estimated to reduce the FY 2019-FY 2029 budget deficit by a further $62 billion. Finally, the debt limit was suspended through August 2021.[14]
What Were the Effects of the BCA?
The BCA resulted in the activation of the sequestration process in 2012, to be implemented January 2013 (later extended to March by the ATRA). The Joint Select Committee on Deficit Reductions was unable to reach an agreement on further budgetary cuts, therefore a $1.2 trillion automatic cut was implemented. Reductions in the cost of servicing the debt account for 18% of the $1.2 trillion. The remainder was spread from FY 2013 to FY 2021 and evenly distributed across defense and non-defense spending, resulting in a $54.7 billion reduction per category per year. Medicare was limited to a 2% reduction.[15] Changes to the duration and levels of the sequester by year are discussed above in reference to the subsequent legislation.
There was a concern related to defense spending that, rather than adhering to the spending caps put in place, the Department of Defense would reallocate spending to the OCO category, which was not subject to the spending caps. Spending related to OCO is hard to define and monitor, leaving significant opportunity for abuse through over allocating spending to the OCO category rather than discretionary defense spending. This would allow the defense sector to avoid a portion of the spending reductions required by the BCA.
However, many of these concerns have not materialized, due in part to the general trend of scaling down military action in the Middle East. OCO spending itself has been falling, from a peak of $194.6 billion in 2008 (28% of total defense spending) to $126.5 billion in 2012 (18% of total defense spending), and $72.5 billion in 2015 (11% of total defense spending). OCO spending has picked up slightly since then, rising to $103.4 billion in 2017 (14% of total defense spending) before falling to approximately $77 billion in both 2018 and 2019 (10% of total defense spending). The majority (92%) of this spending is by the Department of Defense, with USAID and Homeland Security making up the remaining portion.[16]
However, in the FY 2020 proposed budget, OCO spending more than doubled over the previous year to $165 billion. It was explicitly stated that this dramatic increase was intended to make up for cuts to the defense budget from the BCA, with compensatory decreases in OCO and increases in discretionary spending beginning in 2022 after the expiration of the BCA.[17] This led to significant backlash from fiscal conservatives, as it legitimized many of the concerns regarding the OCO spending category that have existed since its exemption from the BCA. This supports the need for more effective regulations regarding the use of OCO or its inclusion in future budgetary limits, as the scale of abuse can be large from this category of spending.
A similar argument could be made regarding emergency spending, which was not subject to the spending caps put in place by the BCA. However, due to the well-defined nature of this category of spending, there have been few concerns of abuse.
Why is This Relevant Now?
Examining the BCA is relevant now given the enormous fiscal policy measures enacted to support businesses and individuals since the onset of the COVID-19 pandemic. While these efforts were necessary to avoid a major contraction in the U.S. economy, they will also significantly increase the level of the debt proportional to GDP.
Congress continues to debate additional stimulus measures as the economic dislocations caused by the pandemic persist. Thus, federal deficits and debt are continuing to grow at a record pace. However, eventually U.S. fiscal policy must move toward a more sustainable path.
BCA: A Useful Framework?
Discretionary spending caps put in place by the BCA are nearing their expiration dates. Does the BCA provide us with a framework for curtailing unsustainable deficits and moving to a sustainable fiscal policy?
Overall, the BCA seems to be a colossal failure as a tool for controlling spending. Since 2013, Congress has passed a series of two-year deals to avoid most of the cuts imposed by the BCA (see Figure 2). In addition, Congress changed the way that they dealt with the debt ceiling. For example, in 2011 when the BCA was implemented, Congress raised the debt ceiling by a specific amount, such as $2.1 trillion under certain circumstances. However, since 2013 Congress has begun suspending the debt ceiling — so that during the suspension period there is no operative ceiling on the debt at all.
While the debt ceiling is a rather useless budget tool, it is clear Congress has no appetite for any kind of constraint on its spending authority. Neither the BCA nor the debt ceiling limit Congress’s ability or will to spend money that is financed with debt (i.e., revenues from future generations). To say that the BCA was ineffective and that it failed to accomplish its original goal is likely an understatement.
Figure 2 — Caps on Total Discretionary Funding and the Changes Made to Them by Recent Bipartisan Budget Acts
Criticisms of Sequestration
Sequestration itself is also controversial, as it is a relatively crude method of budget reductions. It is applied evenly across budget areas, forcing agencies to apply reductions across nonexempt programs. One line of thought praises the imprecise nature of the sequester as a further disincentive to exceed spending caps; others claim that the sequester should be well designed for practical reductions so that if it is reached, it can be better administered and have less distortive effects.[18]
It is important to consider the criticisms of the sequestration process and perhaps develop a more fine-tuned system of budgetary reduction that still serves to encourage programs to adhere to lower spending limits.
Conclusion
The United States has a history of inconsistent attitudes about the budget deficit and federal debt. Candidates and parties often campaign on promises of PAYGO (pay as you go in regard to funding new spending or tax reductions) or austerity that are rarely realized once in office. The COVID-19 crisis was a black swan event, and there is a general consensus that the significant government actions taken were necessary to mitigate the economic effects of the pandemic. Nevertheless, it is important to reflect on the BCA — especially since it has now expired — and Congress and President Biden must decide whether to enact similar legislation moving forward.
While the BCA may appear to have made substantial impact, particularly on reducing growth in the defense budget, that reduction was more likely the result of a greater trend toward demilitarization rather than the efficacy of the BCA. The repeated extensions and modifications through additional legislation indicate that the BCA has not been a particularly effective budgetary tool in capping spending.
Curbing large increases in federal spending for discretionary and nondiscretionary programs will continue to be an important fiscal issue. Efficient and effective policy changes to address unsustainable fiscal trends are critical for continued economic growth and increases in the standard of living for future generations.
Endnotes
[1] December 2007 to June 2009.
[2] https://fred.stlouisfed.org/series/FYGFGDQ188S.
[3] https://www.congress.gov/112/crec/2011/05/31/CREC-2011-05-31.pdf (H3783).
[4] Mindy R. Levit, “The Budget Control Act of 2011: Budgetary Effects of Proposals to Replace the FY2013 Sequester,” Congressional Research Service, December 21, 2012, 13.
[5] Grant A. Driessen, Molly F. Sherlock, and Donald J. Marples, “Debt and Deficits: Spending, Revenue, and Economic Growth,” Congressional Research Service, December 4, 2018, 3.
[6] Mindy R. Levit, “The Budget Control Act of 2011: Budgetary Effects of Proposals to Replace the FY2013 Sequester,” Congressional Research Service, December 21, 2012, 13.
[7] Megan S. Lynch, “Exceptions to the Budget Control Act’s Discretionary Spending Limits,” Congressional Research Service, June 19, 2019, 18.
[8] Grant A. Driessen, “Budgetary Effects of the BCA as Amended: The ‘Parity Principle,’” Congressional Research Service, February 23, 2018, 3.
[9] Bill Heniff, “The American Taxpayer Relief Act of 2012: Modifications to the Budget Enforcement Procedures in the Budget Control Act,” Congressional Research Service, February 4, 2013, 5.
[10] D. Andrew Austin, “The Budget Control Act and Trends in Discretionary Spending,” Congressional Research Service, November 26, 2014, 12.
[11] D. Andrew Austin, “The Budget Control Act and Trends in Discretionary Spending,” Congressional Research Service, November 26, 2014, 13.
[12] Peter G Peterson Foundation, “Analysis: Understanding the Bipartisan Budget Act of 2015,” November 17, 2015, https://www.pgpf.org/analysis/understanding-the-bipartisan-budget-act-of-2015.
[13] Grant A. Driessen, “Budgetary Effects of the BCA as Amended: The ‘Parity Principle,’” Congressional Research Service, February 23, 2018, 3.
[14] Grant A. Driessen, and Megan S Lynch, “The Bipartisan Budget Act of 2019: Changes to the BCA and Debt Limit,” August 5, 2019, 4.
[15] Grant A. Driessen and Marc Labonte, “The Budget Control Act of 2011 as Amended: Budgetary Effects,” Congressional Research Service, December 29, 2015, 24.
[16] Brendan W. McGarry, and Emily M Morgenstern, “Overseas Contingency Operations Funding: Background and Status,” Congressional Research Service, September 6, 2019, 52.
[17] Brendan W. McGarry and Emily M Morgenstern, “Overseas Contingency Operations Funding: Background and Status,” Congressional Research Service, September 6, 2019, 52.
[18] Megan S. Lynch, “Sequestration as a Budget Enforcement Process: Frequently Asked Questions,” Congressional Research Service, December 1, 2015, 8.
This material may be quoted or reproduced without prior permission, provided appropriate credit is given to the author and Rice University’s Baker Institute for Public Policy. The views expressed herein are those of the individual author(s), and do not necessarily represent the views of Rice University’s Baker Institute for Public Policy.